Justice Alive and Well?


This cartoon, Justice under Economics, concerns law and economics in America.  To most of us, law and economics are distinct concepts.  But almost everyone who attended law school in recent decades took a course in law and economics.
This course considered the intersection of the law and economics.  The students learned that economics is a modern social science that seeks to optimize societal production, consumption, and investment.  Their legal curriculum suggested that the law is a codification of the evolving ethical reasoning of society.
The differences between the law and economics were striking.  For example, the law is divided:  by country, by state, by municipality, by jurisdiction, by court, and as to origin (ie. common law versus administrative law).  Unlike law which has many divisions, market economics purports to be a unity: it purports to prescribe what is maximally productive or efficient across cultures and borders.
Economics is modern and progressive when compared with the law.  Much of law is ancient, is cultural, is situational, and is outdated?
The law looks backward for precedents; economics looks forward with forecasts and prescriptions. 

Justice defies measurement; it is case-specific and based in perceptions.  Meanwhile, economics provides neat numerical measures of societal utility (satiety)—if that can be made to represent broad justice.
Here is a science, they learned, that can independently or in tandem with other sciences reduce everything (however tenuously) to a monetary cost or price or value.  For example, an economist might, using the prescriptions of a psychologist, derive the monetary value of a mother lost to a child—if the psychologist’s prescriptions are an adequate substitute for a mother.

They learned that economic theory, like game theory, might suggest more efficient ways to compete and contend in a case or in a courtroom—if maximal monetary gain was justice enough.
Economic arguments, they observed, appeal to something which garners universal sympathy:  human want or need. Sympathies for literal and moral arguments are more heuristic— influenced by one’s experience with the law or moral at issue.

Economics can substitute the cool rationality of digits for the hype, heat, and heft of semantics in legal arguments.  Literal and moral arguments tend to be strident and divisive.  With economics, one can consider what is optimal, productive, and/or efficient--without the divisive freight of moral arguments.
Economics exalts self-interest as service to society; in a courtroom or in a political debate, self-interest is only self-seeking partisanship.

From the perspective of economics, the regulation of law is an externality—something that inhibits or impedes the natural flows of capital and goods.  Economists assert that competitive markets efficiently ration goods and capital; courts don’t; if laws and governments didn’t intrude in economics, societal utility (satiety) would be maximized.
The law students probably came away from the courses with vague perceptions that economics is unassailably mathematical and logical when compared with the law which is ad hoc, political, administrative, unscientific, and sometimes illogical.

During the courses, many of these law students probably made and shared some new and informed resolutions:  to be a prudent lawyer: to generally favor economic arguments as unifying to persons across classes and cultures and to spurn literal or moral arguments as difficult and divisive, to err toward an economic interpretation or execution of the law; to generally avoid a moralizing interpretation or execution of the law; to identify and represent only economic causes so as to have money and reason on one’s side; to only pursue a just cause for as long as it is economic; to retain experts who would provide 'empirical' economic testimony to influence juries; to refuse cases that would pit one against economic collectives like the government and the legal community.
But in general, the classes did not provide the attorneys with the skills to measure economic value.  Without this skill, in practice, the newly minted attorneys and judges would only pursue clients, causes, and legal interpretations that they easily deemed economic or progressive.

Progressively, economics (and law) would enable detachment from literal interpretations and moral arguments when they would be inconvenient, illiberal, or unprogressive.  For example, “just compensation” to be paid to private property owners under the Bill of Rights when private property is taken for public use might be trivialized to “just compensation” as in “just yesterday”, thus losing all the ethical and moral freight of justice and equity, on behalf of an economic client like the state and its public.  It would spare one the duty to represent or defend or even concede a jury trial to a private “holdout” against the state and its public taxpayers because it would be non-economic and unprogressive, however just.  To allow state employees to be accountable for torts, even egregious or criminal torts, would be uneconomic—especially if one was a state judge on a state payroll.  An economic interpretation of the law would spare judges much of the political hazard of rendering justice—because an economic interpretation of law would almost always side with might.
With some reflection, the students probably deduced that:   what is economic generally promotes a welfare state:  it purports to represent what is best for the majority; it generally benefits the masses—often at the expense of the rights of individuals—unless the individual happens to be a Rockefeller or a Rhodes.  Law and economics naturally sides with the rich and the collective poor--to the detriment of the middle class.

Notably, what the law and economics classes probably omitted was a simple observation about the origin and timing of economics.  Relative to the origin of law, economics came late.  In fact, the English rule of law preceded the study of economics by five centuries.  It was in 1297, that the law of the land clause of the Magna Carta was confirmed by Edward I.  It protected persons and property from arbitrary imprisonment and confiscation.  The first study of economics only emerged in 1776 with the publication of The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith.  In other words, the supremacy of law was instated in England and America long before economics emerged.  Much of economic theory was developed in the United States under the auspices of Constitutional law.   This is notable.
Without rules, without the supremacy of law, everyone understood economics:  he prospers who is not prey.  Without protections for property and persons, both were simple prey to power.  Ownership was not secure.  Capital and goods were ephemeral.  Sovereign seizures made physical security (not productivity) paramount.  Efficient activities included hoarding and bribery under this regime.  It was superfluous to consider the efficiency, productivity, and optimization of capital when capital was not secure.

Some centuries after the rule of law had ordered society and economic relationships and interactions, economics arose.  History reveals that the rule of law was the egg; economics was the chicken that hatched from this egg.  The enlightenment of economic science was only enabled by and extended from the rule of law (ie. the Constitution of the United States).

Some would say this observation is tenuous and that the rule of law was an accident observed in a single sample:  history.  An economist, Richard Posner, one of the most cited legal scholars of the 20th century, has suggested that “the rule of law is an accidental and dispensable element of legal ideology".  In other words, he considers the rule of law to be an inexplicable, unprogressive deviation from what is optimal.  Perhaps he considers economics to be other than “an accidental and dispensable element of legal ideology”?
It is nonsense, blindness, and/or treason to propound economic theory as the highest argument or analysis or law or arbiter or government:  to do so is to propound the invisible hand of anarchy.  To do so, is to run against the only sample we have:  history.  To do so, is to reduce all humanity to economic capital.  To do so, is to embrace the centralized planning of society by politicians and economists.  Rule of law would suggest that even science including economic science is beneath the law.

But is that how we actually order our society?  By this transitive:  rule of law  > economics?  Or, is economy foremost?  As a society, haven’t we come to generally shun what is literal, cultural, political, and religious and favor what is economic, productive, and efficient?
What is our dominant identity as Americans?  Is our chief identity economic?  Is it that:  of the credit-enabled consumer, of the profiteer with or without produce and with or without work, of the insatiable internationalist or industrialist, of the uncensurable government employee or unionist, of the entitled welfare recipient or social-security retiree?  Or, do we identify with the patriots to whom freedom under law was so dear that they purchased it with their money and lives and reputations—for us?  Do we value the rule of law above our jobs, credit, investments, entitlements, profits, industries, even our temporary security?  Or, for the sake of jobs or pensions or profits, will we assent to the suspension and subversion of some laws that protect the property and persons of others?

For the sake of societal gain, economics (ie. Keynesianism) is used to justify all sorts of extra-legal and otherwise unconscionable redistributions of property, rights, and legal priorities—especially in times of crisis.  For example, to avert an economic crisis and to stimulate the mortgage market, economists have suggested that borrowers ought to be allowed to breach mortgage contracts—but only if their mortgage is past due—never mind the social cost to justice, to the lender, and to other borrowers.  Politicians, informed by central planners, have intervened to prop up industries like banking, insurance, and the auto industry and to develop industries like green energy.  Apparently, this intervention has not improved the economy.  Much of this activity has contravened existing law.  It has made investment in the American economy uncertain and unprofitable.  Worse, it has redistributed wealth without regard to justice or the rule of law.  Worse, wealth has been redistributed away from those who uphold or would uphold the rule of law (ie. the middle class).
Under law and economics, without moorings to morality, the legal system lacks the will to check this lawlessness.  Consider the events of 2008.   Some of our law students became politicians, judges, and regulators—the same individuals who reversed laws and deferred regulations and structured rulings to deregulate the financial markets, concerned that laws would check the efficiency of the financial markets that ultimately fleeced so many Americans in a financial crisis that continues to reverberate.  In so doing, they propounded economic theory as ascendant to the rule of law.

Certainly, for the rich and powerful, raw economics is more efficient than egalitarian laws.  Perhaps economics and law has contributed to the increasingly unequal distribution of income in America?  Apparently, the rich are getting richer right alongside economic interpretations of the law.  And the poor are getting poorer (and the prisons are burgeoning) right alongside economic interpretations of the law.
But if economic interpretations of law are unjust, if they confound the checks on government that protect the rule of law, what will be our basis for law and justice?  Can a consensus be formed based on morality when common sense and conscience are publicly confounded?  In its true light, law and economics ought to be viewed for what it is:  a valiant but impoverished attempt by the legal community to prop up law in the absence of morality as a substitute for displaced absolutes like God, truth, and right.  In place of moral absolutes, economics exalts self-interest as enlightenment in the judge and in the judged.

This simplifies justice.  It reduces it to sums.  It appeals to our selfish natures.  It rebuffs guilt when we encounter inequality:  we rationalize that the poverty of others is self-inflicted--perhaps because they have refused the enlightenment of pure self-interest?
But isn’t it also self-interest that animates nature’s predators?  Are we, then, under economics, animals who accidentally acquired a conscience?  Would our courtroom, economic, political, religious, and cultural disputes be better reconciled by natural processes that leave one “red in tooth and claw”?

Here is my economic forecast for a country that puts economics above the rule of law and morality:  hunger and fear.  Don’t expect good sense or justice or morality to prevail in a society where the only law applied or upheld is the science of secular economics.  In fact, if constitutional law is successfully subverted by law and economics, if economics becomes our only unity, conscience, and constraint expect to turn the calendar back about 1,000 years to a period that resembles the Spanish Inquisition.


God bless you,


Whoseman

No comments:

Post a Comment